Showing posts with label Quantitative Easing. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Quantitative Easing. Show all posts

Thursday, 25 June 2015

Interest Rates – low but not low enough

Interest rates may not be low enough to get us on the road to recovery but falling prices should help

Something strange is afoot in the economy.  With interest rates at record lows in many countries, borrowing should be booming and saving on the decline but the opposite is true.  This suggests that the economy remains out of kilter without interest rates being able to set the right balance between savings and investment.  Instead, the shortfall in demand due to limited investment and weak spending may be dragging down prices as a means to put the economy back to health.  

Not so free market

The self-healing ability of any economy is one of the central tenants of economic theory.  Prices adjust as a means for the economy adapting to any changes.  For example, an increase in the supply of bananas will trigger a fall in prices and more people eating bananas.  A rise in companies looking for software experts would drive up their wages (the price for labour) and the number of people wanting to learn more about computers.  Through changes in these prices, the economy moves toward an equilibrium where everything is at appropriate levels.

Interest rates act in the same way acting as the “price of money” to make sure that there is neither too much nor too little savings or investment.  Lower interest rates are used to make borrowing cheaper and savings less worthwhile.  This was the course of action taken by central banks in order to stimulate the economy by attempting to boost investment (funded by lending) and spur on more consumption (due to lower savings).  Quantitative easing adds to this by giving banks more money to lend and less need to entice people to leave money in the bank.

Still waiting

The continued wait for a robust recovery suggests that something remains amiss.  The lack of appetite among companies to expand their operations by borrowing is both a cause of and caused by weak demand in the overall economy.  Spending by consumers is also faltering with people happy to let money mount up in the bank despite the low returns on savings.  The high levels of household debt that still persist are another reason for consumers to hold back from spending.

The persistence of the state of low investment and high savings suggests that monetary policy has not been enough to get the economy back on the right track (although it has helped to prevent a financial collapse).  A further loosening of monetary policy is not on the books for most central banks.  Interest rates cannot be lowered much further considering that negative interest rates are difficult to implement.  Quantitative easing also seems to have run its course while increasing creating negative side effects

Where to next?

The inability of interest rates to adjust is hampering a return to economic growth.  With interest rates not able to go any lower, it may be the case that it is prices which are instead moving to get the economy back to equilibrium.  That is, rather than interest rates falling to balance out weak lending and growing savings, prices are being depressed by the lacklustre economy.  The hopes for economic recovery rely on cheaper prices spurring on more spending thanks to consumers felling richer.  Further impetus would result from the extra spending helping to push up investment and lift the economy to better match the current level of interest rates.

This route back to recovery may take time considering that any decline in prices will be limited and wage gains have yet to take off.  There are ways to push this along of which easiest way would be for governments to temporarily increase spending.  Money used for investments in infrastructure or training and R&D in new technologies would be worthwhile at a time of low interest rates.  Another alternative would be for central banks to use their money-printing capabilities to transfer cash to consumers.  This more radical option would provide a short-term boost to spending.  Sometimes we all need a little bit extra to get us back on track and the economy is no different.

Thursday, 14 May 2015

Emerging Markets – Caught in the Crossfire

US monetary policy has missed its mark and it is a handful of emerging markets that look set to pay the price

The big guns of monetary policy used to combat sluggish economic growth are about to be put away but the real damage may be just about to kick in.  The Federal Reserve adopted loose monetary policy to get the US economy moving again but it is elsewhere where the effects have been felt the most.  Having benefited more from the loose monetary policy than the intended target, some emerging markets look set to suffer as a policy reversal prompts US investors to stage a destructive retreat back home.

Danger zone

The proverbial printing presses at central banks are like the heavy artillery of monetary policy.  Central banks such as the Federal Reserve had been pumping out cash to buy bonds as part of quantitative easing.  Yet, the US economy had failed to fire up with companies unwilling to invest while spending remains weak.  Investors with cash in hand turned their sights overseas and targeted emerging markets where economic growth was still perky. 

The surplus US dollars helped to lower interest rates for borrowers in many countries which had not gotten caught up in the global financial crisis.  The reduced borrowing costs pushed up lending elsewhere despite not having the same effects in the US economy.  The muted effects of monetary policy in the domestic economy prompted the Federal Reserve to unleash even more firepower.  Money, like some things, is fine in moderation but the bombardment of US dollars inadvertently created its own minefield. 

Borrowers in emerging market were only given access to cheap cash by borrowing in US dollars for a short period of time.  This was fine as long as the prospects for the US economy were poor and US dollars were readily available.  But any significant improvement in the US economy would see investors shift their money back.  A stronger US economy would also push up the value of the US dollar and make it tougher for overseas borrowers to pay off any debts in US dollars. 

Collateral damage

Like solider stationed in a hostile region, investors were set up to bail when the opportunity arose.  Just the mere mention by the Federal Reserve in May 2013 that quantitative easing might be coming to an end was enough to trigger a rush by investors to get their money out.  Six months of market volatility followed even though quantitative easing did not actually end until October 2014.  With the Federal Reserve now mulling lifting interest rates up from their low levels, more upheaval seems likely.

This is because money often does more damage on the way out compared to the gains when it is initially welcomed.  Yet, the lure of cheap cash is too much to ignore.  Even the financial sectors in richer countries have shown themselves to be unable to cope when too much money is on offer.  Less developed banking systems in emerging markets are often even worse at putting any cash to good use.  This increases the likelihood that many borrowers will struggle when US dollars are harder to come by. 

As the aftermath of the global financial crisis has made painfully clear, a swift end to a lending boom is not something easy to get over.  In its attempts to deal with an US economy sagging under the weight of excess debt, the Federal Reserve has inflicted the same woes on others who are less able to deal with the consequences.  Like any form of warfare, it is the innocent victims that suffer the most.

Wednesday, 6 May 2015

Quantitative Easing – Getting less from more

The European Central Bank has been late to try quantitative easing and may find that additional euros cannot buy much relief

We all have the tendency to rely on the tried and true tricks we have found helpful in the past even when their usefulness has faded.  This also seems true of central banks who have come to rely on quantitative easing even though its effects show signs of fading.  Even the initial boost provided by the first attempts at quantitative easing was limited and the situation has deteriorated amid its continued application.  As the last major central bank to give it a go, the European Central Bank will not get much return from any extra cash. 

Why more is not always more

Economist should know that repeating the same policies does not always work considering a well-used idea in economic theory known as diminishing returns.  This concept refers to the way in which more of the same often comes with fewer additional benefits.  Economists use this to describe why the second plate of ice cream does not taste as good as the first or why one more cook in a crowded kitchen doesn’t necessarily improve the food. 

Printing more money, which is the basis for quantitative easing, sounds like a sure-fire way to generate economic growth but any economy can only handle so much money.  The world is already awash with cash even before central banks started with quantitative easing.  This means that every additional dollar, euro, or pound printed as part of quantitative easing is being added to an already substantial pile of cash.  With money already being hoarded by many companies and governments not wanting to spend more cash, there is not much use for any more.

No need for more

With the meagre effects of quantitative easing on the wane, it was the earlier versions that would have generated the most bang for each additional buck.  It was the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England that tried out the first rounds of quantitative easing – the goal was to push investors away from government bonds to more risky investments such as corporate bonds or stocks.  The hope was that this would help provide companies with easier access to cash and to perk up investors by boosting share prices. 

Not all of the extra dollars and pounds would have stayed local but also headed overseas to find places to earn more money.  This meant that the effects of quantitative easing would have been felt far beyond the countries where the cash was originally coming from.  It has been helpful in places such as Portugal and Spain with overseas investors buying bonds issued by the Portuguese and Spanish governments as worries about Europe eased.


With the effects of quantitative easing having already spilled across international borders, there is not much more to be gained from even more cash.  As such, the additional euros coming out of the European Central Bank following the recent launch of quantitative easing in Europe may not amount to much.  Any further action may also be limited as the saga over whether or not to implement quantitative easing has highlighted how the European Central Bank only has limited room for manoeuvre when running in opposition to Germany.  Now, more than ever, it is time to try something new.

Thursday, 16 April 2015

Monetary Policy – where has the magic gone?

The European Central Bank tries to cast another spell to save the Eurozone but its magic has been stolen

Monetary policy is like magic – you have to use tricks to get people into believing what you want them to believe.  Both magicians and central banks apply various devices to convince their audience that they can pull off amazing feats.  A bit of showmanship can be crucial in creating an aura of the fantastical when your powers are actually rather limited.  Central banks have pulled this off in the past but quantitative easing by the European Central Bank is more likely to show that it does not have any rabbits left to pull out of the hat.

Trying to work magic

Your Neighbourhood Economist likes to look back fondly to an era when central banks had the financial market enthralled with their mastery of all things economic.  This admiration was won the hard way in the 1980s by bringing double-digit inflation back to more manageable levels and ushering in an era where the booms and busts seemed to have past.  But central banks have been taken down a notch by their inability to revive the economy after the global financial crisis. 

Slashing of interest rates has not worked as high levels of debt meant that no one wanted to borrow. Upping the ante, central banks tried pumping money into the financial system through quantitative easing.  The effect on the actual economy due to quantitative easing also looks to be limited at a time when there is already a lot of spare cash in the financial system.  Financial markets were buoyed by quantitative easing but a side effect has been the potential for heightened volatility in the financial markets

With few other options seen as viable, quantitative easing has gone from an unconventional measure to the mainstay policy for central banks despite questions over its usefulness.  The European Central Bank has been slow to try its hand at quantitative easing even though the Eurozone economy was struggling more than most.  This was because Germany (who had initially done well despite its neighbours being in crisis) was firmly against the central bank in Europe printing cash to buy government bonds.  It was only after a further considerable deterioration in the prospects for the Eurozone (as well as that of Germany itself) that the European Central Bank to override this opposition.  

No more magic left

The European Central Bank has been put at a disadvantage considering that the other big central banks have already tried to work their magic through quantitative easing.  Investors are becoming harder to impress having already seen central banks pull off similar tricks.  To maintain the wow factor, quantitative easing has needed to get bigger and bigger.  The central bank in Japan pledged to double the money supply within two years but had to offer up even more cash when its initial plans proved to be lacking. 

The European Central Bank cannot compete on scale as it has to perform magic with one hand behind its back due to the political constraints within the Eurozone.  Any extra boost using the element of surprise was also dented by the protracted process as the European Central Bank and Germany squabbled publicly over quantitative easing in the months before the policy was launched. 

The fractious politics in Europe has sapped power from the central bank who had previously been the main shining light in saving the Eurozone.  Political squabbles have highlighted the limited power at the disposal of the European Central Bank.  It is like a magician who is being sabotaged by their own assistant – it will take more than magic to escape this spell.

Thursday, 11 December 2014

Getting more from Monetary Policy

Japan has made lots of mistakes and it is time that Europe learnt from them

We can all learn from watching others make mistakes and the experiences of Japan continue to provide valuable lessons.  Japan has stumbled into another recession following a hike in taxes to fix the government’s finances.  The other key policy doing the rounds in Japan, using expansive monetary policy to put an end to deflation, also seems to be flagging.  It is Europe that has most to learn from the unfortunate trials and tribulations in Japan since many of the same problems are shared by both.  What should Europe do to avoid making the same mistakes and decades of stagnation?

Following in the same footsteps

Japan has been hit first with many of the same problems that are increasingly expected to plague Europe and other Western countries.  For starters, new-borns in Japan are increasingly outnumbered by pensioners which have pushed the population into decline in recent years with an aversion to immigration further accentuating this trend.  This translates to fewer workers to provide the taxes needed for the rising costs involved with taking care of old people.  The situation is made worse by government debt which is already more than double GDP due to years of inefficient government spending.

Japanese consumer prices have been falling for years as a reflection of the weak demand.  There are few opportunities to profit from in Japan due to the falling population and even Japanese firms are looking elsewhere to invest.  Weak global demand means that even one of Japan’s strengths, exporting, offers only limited respite even with a weaker yen due to its loose monetary policy.  All of this means that the Japanese economy itself is like a tottery pensioner - even a small rise of sales tax from 5% to 8% was enough to push Japan back into recession.  This does not bode well for Europe where the economy is sputtering along due to many of the same problems while the governments there are also trying to get a grip on their finances.

Trying different directions

Having been stuck with these problems for longer, policy makers in Japan are increasingly more aggressive in coming up with solutions.  The current prime minister, Shinzo Abe, launched a raft of new measures dominated by a massive expansion of the money supply to target falling prices.  This new aggressive approach to monetary policy was facilitated by the government installing a new governor to the Bank of Japan who was willing to give up its independence and toe the line.

This is the complete opposite to the situation in Europe.  The head of the European Central Bank is eager to do more with monetary policy but is prevented from doing so by the German government.  German politicians want to reforms to come first due to an expectation that their neighbours will not implement the necessary policies. Whereas, in Japan, the aim was to use the loose monetary policy to help build momentum that will allow the government to implement reforms. 

Yet, the Abe government has been disappointing in its reform efforts (as Your Neighbourhood Economist predicted) and this will bolster the stance taken by Germany.  With the Bank of Japan finding it tough to generate sufficient inflation despite a rapidly expanding money supply through quantitative easing, many will question about the reasons behind using a similar policy in Europe.  Central banks are struggling to have much influence in a world that is already awash with surplus cash.  

Time for Plan C

It seems like the key lesson from Japan is that monetary policy cannot do much by itself.  Japan still languishes despite the best efforts of the central bank as the Abe government shirks the much needed measures to free up the economy.  Yet, bullying countries in Europe to reform by withholding the full extent of monetary policy is not helpful either.  A grand bargain marrying reforms with looser monetary policy, as was supposed to be the case in Japan, seems the obvious solution. 

This takes more political willpower when the many countries of Europe are involved but is not something beyond the realms of possibility.  Ironically, the chances for such a deal may be improving as deflation becomes more of a concerns and the economic stagnation in Europe also spreads to Germany.  Japan has already paid the price for years of economic mismanagement – there is no reason for Europe to do the same.

Monday, 14 July 2014

Question – Interest rates

In response to an inquiry from a reader, Your Neighbourhood Economist explains how low interest rates should have but didn’t affect the economy (with a surprising culprit)

Your Neighbourhood Economist was pleasantly surprised to have a proverbial knock at the door (a photo of which was posted on the blog recently along with an email address for questions) with the following inquiry on interest rates…

I read your blog entry on BOE interest rate hike and needed an opinion. I'm not a finance student but am trying to understanding why something so unusual is happening with the BOE interest rate. You have explained why there is a need to hold the rate low at the moment, seeing there isn't enough inflation yet (as posted in UK Interest Rates – putting off the inevitable). But could you explain to me in layman's terms how this has affected our economy and what other solutions could have been used?

Interest rates are a hot topic at the moment with changes afoot at the Bank of England.  Sometime over the next six to twelve months, the UK central bank is likely to raise its benchmark interest rate off its record low of 0.5% where it has been for more than 5 years.  Low interest rates are the most common way that central banks will try to raise economic growth.  The theory behind this is that cheaper loans will push businesses and households into borrowing money and this extra spending will boost the economy. 

Good in theory but not in practice

In practice, things have not worked out so well.  Businesses have held off taking out loans due to uncertainty over the future direction of the economy.  Companies need to be assured of a decent return from any investment which will typically only make money over the span of several years.  Worries about the future earning potential of any new operations have outweighed the lower costs of borrowing money to invest.   As a result, business lending in the UK has fallen for seven consecutive years with companies preferring to hoard cash instead. 

The main benefactor of low interest rates has been the property market.  House prices in London held up despite the global financial crisis and added to the myth that property values never fall.  So once the worst of the crisis was over, low mortgage rates prompted many to scramble to buy property.  The buoyant housing market has boosted the economy a bit by making people who own property feel richer and spend more.  But more mortgages only pushes up house prices rather than making the economy more productive as investment by businesses would have done.

So the actual effect from low interest rates has been less than hoped.  This resulted in central banks also using quantitative easing – creating new money to buy bonds and other financial assets.  The aim of quantitative easing is increase the amount of money in the economy and help out the banking sector.   Quantitative easing too has been somewhat of a disappointment with few places for the extra cash to be put to good use.  The banking sector typically acts as one of the main means to move cash around the economy but banks have had to focus on their own survival.  The surplus of cash has created its own problems such as distortions in the financial markets which may cause trouble in the future.

Other solutions…?

With businesses not spending and mortgages not adding much to the economy, the obvious solution would be for government to make up the shortfall.  A fiscal stimulus is the typical response to a slowdown in the economy with the extra spending by government making up for weak demand from consumers and businesses.  Yet, government finances in the UK and elsewhere were already stretched before the crisis and deteriorated further with higher welfare payments and falling tax revenues following the crisis.

The Eurozone crisis from 2010 resulted in investors shunning any countries with high levels of government debt.  This prompted the UK government to launch its austerity program with the hope convincing investors that it would sort out its finances.  The plan worked in that the interest rates on UK government debt remained low (also with help from quantitative easing) unlike some countries in Europe such as Ireland and Spain.  However, cuts to government spending hurt the economy and prolong the slump in the economy while also ironically making even more cutbacks necessary.

Still struggling

Getting ourselves out of trouble following the global financial crisis was always going to be tough going.  Recessions stemming from banking crises are typically longer than normal recessions as it takes time to work down the excessive levels of debt and fix the banks.  Less expected was how the economic recovery has been further hampered by ineffective and lacklustre policies. 

Fiscal policy has been working in reverse and the UK government should do more to boost the economy considering that investors are no longer so worried about government debt.  The Bank of England could have done more with monetary policy considering that it can print as much money as it likes but it held back due to misplaced concerns about inflation.  Your Neighbourhood Economist would have liked to have seen more spending by the government and quantitative easing going straight into the economy.

Perhaps the biggest factor holding back the recovery is that economists are slow learners.  Policies such as quantitative easing are new and have helped but more could have been done if economists had not been so caught up with their own ideas.  It is of some consolidation that lessons from the Great Depression (such as the bank bailouts) have been applied to ensure that a similar type of crises has resulted in less fallout.  We can only hope that this crisis is bad enough to ensure better policy in the future.  


(Please add any further questions on this topic using the comments section at the bottom of the page or email any inquiries on different issues related to the economy to Your.Neighbourhood.Economist@gmail.com)

Tuesday, 24 June 2014

Monetary Policy – Surgery Needed

Current monetary policy is still primitive and will remain so without making use of new measures such as macroprudential policies

Monetary policy has come a long way but it is still in its initial stages of development.  Serious shortcomings mean that the tools of monetary policy are still rudimentary just as those of medicine were crude in the past.  In the same way that leeches would be prescribed for every ailment in medieval times, central banks have tended to rely solely on interest rates to manage the economy.  The tendency to “reach for the leeches” is still with us even though the global financial crisis has highlighted the flaws inherent in this approach and a range of new techniques for managing the economy have been made available.

Learning some hard lessons

Doctors often did more harm than good in antiquity due to a lack of understanding of the workings of the human body.  With our knowledge of the economy also deficient in places, economists may be guilty of causing similar damage.  Hubris led economists to believe that booms and busts could be eliminated but their faith was shown to be spectacularly misplaced.  Despite this, economists have been slow to adjust their view of the world even though their remedies are proving both ineffective and costly.

The global financial crisis and its aftermath have taught us a few valuable lessons.  The limitations of using interest rates to moderate the business cycle (both before and after recessions) are now apparent.  Higher interest rates do little to temper lending when both bankers and borrowers want more debt.  It is also becoming clear that different sectors of the economy react to interest rates in different ways.  Consumers have shown themselves willing to take on excessive debt in order to spend or to buy property.  On the other hand, businesses cannot always be enticed to borrow for investment when the economy is weak. 

The limits of monetary policy have been laid bare by the faltering economic recovery.  Low interest rates and cheap cash have spurred on some lending but not the right type to generate sustainable economic growth.  Households have taken on debt to buy property (which mostly just increases prices) rather than businesses or the government borrowing to make the economy more productive.  Surplus funds have also built up prices in the stock market which, while somewhat beneficial in the short term, will create problems down the line.  The abundance of cash in the financial system may also reduce the effectiveness of central banks’ control over interest rates

For a better world

Monetary policy needs to continue to develop as economists learn more about the economy and how it reacts to different policies.  Manipulating interest rates is a blunt instrument that is applied across the whole economy.  Interest rates need to be raised eventually but it seems rash to do so in response to distortions in certain sectors.  An early interest rate hike has been proposed as a countermeasure to the booming UK property market.  Yet, this is like chopping off an arm to treat an infected finger.

A more measured approach would be preferable but will take time to realise.  Techniques such as minimally invasive surgery have been developed in medicine over many years and economists should aim for similar progress in monetary policy.  Disparities between policies in theory and practice mean that trial and error will be necessary.  Using a still sickly economy to trial new policy options may seem reckless.  Yet experimentation is the main route to breaking fresh ground even in medicine where there are actual lives at risk.  Forward guidance is an example of a policy which seemed useful in theory but whose application was fraught with issues.

A wider range of policies would help deal with problems now and in the future with greater effectiveness.  These two goals can be achieved by the Bank of England trialling the much-discussed macroprudential policies such as caps on mortgages and other limits on property lending.  Having a greater range of options allows for better tailoring of policy while targeted measures enable greater freedom in setting interest rates to reflect the overall economy.  Just as modern medicine has had to advance beyond leeches, future monetary policy will need to progress past what we currently have and such an evolution will only happen as a result of taking bold actions today.

Monday, 23 June 2014

Monetary Policy – Losing its Power?

With the finance sector already awash with cash, we can no longer rely on central banks to help us out of trouble

After having worked like a charm for a long time, monetary policy now seems to be losing its mojo.  The source of power for central banks mainly comes through their tricks of printing money and controlling interest rates.  With many governments mired in debt, it has only been the wizardry of central banks that has stood between us and a greater tragedy.  It is of great concern that the capabilities of the once almighty central banks to manipulate the economy are under threat from the large amounts of liquidity in the financial system.  The spells with which central banks hold sway over the economy may amount to little more than illusion when there is already lots of cash around.

Where has the magic gone?

The power to create money seems nothing short of sorcery; however, the rise of digital cash means that it is in fact easier than ever.  Central banks have even lost their monopoly over generating electronic cash with normal banks able to pull off the same trick by making loans.  It was thought that control of interest rates would be sufficient to steer the economy through any ups and downs.  Yet central banks left interest rates too low in line with their narrow focus on keeping inflation in check and banks were free to churn out loans at an unprecedented rate.  The prices of assets such as property have surged upward as a result but only until the inevitable crash in prices.

Central banks stepped in with record low interest rates and new policy tricks such as quantitative easing.  Yet these measures lack potency considering that cash was already cheap and in abundance.  Both banks and businesses hoarded cash – the former worried about their own survival while the latter had few investment options available due to the weak economy.  To add to this, many emerging markets such as China had been building up massive reserves since well before the global financial crisis. 

With the international financial system already flooded with cash, it has been no surprise that monetary policy has not worked as well as expected.  It has been like trying to use sweets to modify the behaviour of a child that lives in a candy shop.  Instead of being much help, the extra funds from central banks have seen the financial markets deformed and distorted as if suffering from some form of voodoo.  Some emerging markets have also suffered from this black magic with their banking sectors unable to handle the volume of cash on offer.

Nothing up their sleeves

Central banks have been looking to develop new powers to influence different sectors of banking.  The Bank of England has been given greater scope to deal with a runaway property market.  Yet, the central bank seems ill at ease with its new policy options, such as restrictions on mortgages, and prefers to rely on its old act of manipulating interest rates.  If central banks no longer have the power to bewitch the economy, it will be tougher to clean up after a crisis like the one we have just been through.

This shifts the goal of policy to stopping problems forming rather than merely attempting to limit the ensuing trouble.  Restricting the dark arts conjured up by banks will be essential to preventing future disasters.  The fairy-tale time when we could believe in the magic of central banks may have passed – we will need to rein in the wicked elements of the economy now that there is nothing to save us from potential misfortune.

Tuesday, 17 June 2014

Stock Markets – Calm for now

Following a rising stock market is an easy way to make money but share prices can only defy gravity for so long

Something strange is in the air among investors – a pervading sense of calm.  Volatility in financial markets has dropped off while stock prices are near record highs.  These conditions seem out of place at a time when there are a number of reasons to be jittery - the economic recovery is far from assured and central banks are set to raise interest rates.  The buoyancy of the financial markets says more about the habits of investors than the actual state of the economy. 

One defining feature of investing is that it can be easier to make money by following trends rather than fighting against market momentum.  The only problem is that the trends become a force in themselves and can push prices too far either up or down.  This effect can only be temporary as markets must revert back to normality at some point.  This leaves investors caught between making money when times are good and making a getaway before profits are wiped out.  This day is drawing closer.  Your Neighbourhood Economist can’t predict when it might happen, only that a reckoning is likely to be just around the corner.

It’s complicated
Financial markets are notoriously hard to read.  Theory tells us that the prices of shares are based on a combination of all available relevant information.  Yet one of the most pertinent reasons for buying or selling is the past price movements.  Financial assets are one of the few things that we buy more of as the price rises and are more likely to sell when the price falls.  This can often override other considerations such as whether a company is expected to see its profits grow in the future.  Base instincts such as greed and fear can also take over and distort our investment decisions.
The tech boom and bust just over a decade ago was a classic example of this.  Investors threw money into start-ups whose ability to generate revenue was questionable.  You did not even have to believe that the Internet would revolutionize business, just that others would and that these others would keep buying so that you could make a tidy profit and sell up.  Thus, prices often deviate from what shares in a company might actually be worth depending on the likelihood that someone else might be willing to pay more for the shares sometime in the future. 
This is not to say that money cannot be made by holding onto shares in profitable and well-managed firms.  Yet such an investment policy will only work out in the long term with the timing of when to buy and sell also being crucial.  The bulk of investors, however, are not trading in shares over the long term.  Professional investors looking after other peoples’ money tend to actively buy and sell to take advantage of short-term trends.  This proactive approach is also used justify (and amplify) their considerable fees despite often being unable to outperform market benchmarks.
Actually, it's even more complicated

Gauging where shares might be heading is further complicated by the current expansive monetary policy.  An abundance of cash in the financial system means that people wanting to buy financial assets are never far away.  Pushing share prices to unrealistic values is just one example of how monetary policy is creating problems.  Policy makers need consumers in an optimistic mood to get spending up and creating extra wealth through the stock market is one of the few ways of getting us in a more cheerful mood.  It can only provide a short-term boost and might work in the opposite direction when this policy is reversed.  The jolt from the inevitable interest rate hike which is likely to disrupt the market calm may result in more than just some investors losing their easy gains.

Wednesday, 4 June 2014

Economics – more religion than science?

Economists claim to offer salvation but the tenets of economics need reforming before we can be saved

Economics is sometimes like a religion in that its adherents keep the faith irrespective of evidence to the contrary.  The global financial crisis has tested the conviction of many economists but few seem ready to renounce their previous beliefs.  This might seem strange with a discipline that aims to be more like a science but there are factors which mean economics relies more on faith than on facts.  Considering the positions of power held by economists, we can only hope that the moment of revelation is not too far off. 

In Markets We Trust

Economics claims to offer a path to the Promised Land.  The role of God is assumed by the concept of the invisible hand which prophesies that markets will bring about the most favourable outcomes in terms of output and prices.  One of the most sacred beliefs in economics is that we must defer to the invisible hand as much as possible.  Economists help this along, with central banks keeping down inflation while governments open up their economies to global markets.   This ushered in over two decades of unprecedented economic progress until financial turmoil struck like a plague in 2008. 

Yet, despite the economic Armageddon that followed, economists have remained stubbornly tied to the same creed.  The response to the financial crisis has relied on the traditional tonic of lower interest rates with newer orthodoxy calling for the use of quantitative easing when conventional measures did not work.  Central banks have stuck with these policies despite the resulting growing distortions in the financial markets which would be anathema for economists in normal times. 

Believing in false idols

One element which makes economics more like a religion and less like a science is that it is difficult to prove when someone is wrong.  Scientific theories can be tested by experiments carried out in laboratories or similar places where the conditions can be kept in check.  Economic hypotheses cannot be proven in such controlled environments.  The sheer volume of transactions by consumers and firms means that there may be any number of reasons behind a certain outcome.  The impossibility of isolating specific cause and effect relationships means that truths in economics can only be subjective. 

This means that economists can piously hold onto their previous ideas on how the economy works despite any evidence to the contrary.  Economists tend to become wedded to their ideas as they hone them over many years in long careers in academia.  Any newcomers to economic are also indoctrinated into the existing dogma with little scope for breaking out of the mould.  The current generation of economics students have risen up in arms against being taught theories that have little relevance to economic events.

One of the more old-fashioned ideas that economists cling to is a fear of inflation.  The full range of tools for monetary stimulus has not been available as central banks have been adamant that inflation should not be allowed to get out of control.  This stems from psychological scars in the minds of economists due to damage done by inflation in a bygone era (the 1970s).  Europe has suffered the most under this economic fanaticism and has had to deal with the added difficulties of the Eurozone crisis with few policy options available

It is not a coincidence that the global economy and economic theory are both stagnating at the same time – economic deliverance for us all may depend on a second coming of economics in a more practical form.


Tuesday, 20 May 2014

Central Banks – false illusion of power

The Bank of England shows how little central banks can do with their limited resources

Everyone looks to central banks as the custodians of the economy.  Once upon a time, central banks were regarded as having almost mythical powers to control the forces of the economy.  However, this fairy tale was shattered by the global financial crisis and central banks have since been trying to regain their previous status as economic titans.  Central banks have fought back with extra powers such as quantitative easing which have helped bolster their popularity.  In contrast, the trouble that the Bank of England is having in dealing with the conflicting problems of a fragile recovery and a booming housing market shows central banks at their most impotent.

The myth and the reality

Much of what central banks do relies on creating a belief in their resolve and ability to call on seemingly unlimited resources.  Chronic inflation in the 1970s was reined in by central banks flexing their muscles and inflation has stayed low ever since.  Even in the throes of a crisis, the European Central Bank kept the Eurozone together merely by proclaiming that it was willing to do “whatever it takes” to do so.

With the power to print money, central banks have the godlike ability to create something out of thin air.  It is often only the ideas of economics that keep central banks from unleashing the full force of their powers.  The ability to summon money from the ether is of limited use when most economists are scared of rising inflation following an increase in the supply of money.  Economics has also restricted central banks to operating only in a small arena, which reduces their capacity to act as a power for good.

One example of this is quantitative easing which helped ease the pain over the downturn but came with side effects.  The purchases of bonds through quantitative easing helped to shore up the financial markets but did little to alleviate a chronic shortage of demand in the actual economy.  A slightly different way of using quantitative easing could have had more punch with less mess but also came with the possibility of some inflation. 

Like something from Greek tragedy 

The Bank of England operates in this world of possibilities, but with only limited options.  It has made use of what was available (low interest rates and quantitative easing) but the economic recovery has struggled to gain much traction even after five years.  Yet, the consequences of its policies have shown up as a housing market boom at a time when the Bank of England still has its hands full nursing the economy.

One thing that the Bank of England is missing is a bit of help from the government.  Not only is the government dragging down the economy with its austerity measures, but it is creating problems with policies such as Help to Buy which stoke up the property market just as the central bank is praying for it to cool down.  For all of their potential power, central banks still have to steer clear of politics putting any criticism of government policy out of bounds.  The government with all of its populist tendencies still trumps an institution established to look out for the long term health of the economy. 

Instead, the Bank of England and its governor, Mark Carney, have tried to use the media to communicate their concerns about the property market.  However, this is having little effect as the Bank of England can be ignored since there are few actions it could actually take to back up its words.  Its main weapon would be higher interest rates but the economic recovery is seen as not yet being strong enough.  It would be a shame to see the Bank of England fall from grace battling a wayward government and a run-away property market but it will take a heroic feat to stop that happening.

UK Interest Rates – putting off the inevitable

Higher interest rates are on their way but are still too scary to talk about

An economic recovery is a timid creature that can be scared away merely by saying the wrong thing.  That is the implication behind statements coming out of the Bank of England which has played down the possibility of higher interest rates.  The Bank of England cut interest rates to a record low more than five years ago, but improvements in the UK economy mean that we are nearing a time when interest rates will have to return to “normal” levels.  This may still be a fair way off considering that the Bank of England seems to think that the subject is too frightening to even discuss.

Why are higher interest rates needed?

It may seem funny to talk about fears in the market at a time when UK stocks are near record highs.  However, many of the gains over the last few years have come with the support of central banks.  Low interest rates coupled with quantitative easing have prompted investors to dive into the stock market in search of better returns.  The property market has also benefited with asset prices in general booming despite the weak economy.

The hope has been that the extra wealth generated as a result of rising asset prices would prompt people to spend more.  This plan has worked to a certain extent with consumer spending being one of the main drivers behind the economic recovery in Britain.  Yet it has also created a problem in that a reversal in this new-found wealth will have the opposite effect and send consumers running for cover.  This line of thought suggests that it would be great if interest rates could be kept at the current low levels.  However, an increase is inevitable.

The main concern for any central bank is that cheap borrowing will create excessive demand and push up inflation.  Your Neighbourhood Economist has argued that these worries about inflation tend to be overblown.  A more pressing problem comes from the UK property market.  Housing prices have surged upward, recovering at a rate considerably faster than that of the overall economy.  This suggests that such gains in property prices are likely to be unsustainable and may cause trouble in the future.  This situation is made worse by the UK government being unwilling to offer much help in stimulating the economy.

What is so scary?

The central bank is caught at a junction where the long-term costs of low interest rates are becoming more obvious relative to the short-term benefits.  Acting too soon could damage a still fragile recovery while problems such as the booming property market could get out of hand if interest rates stay low for too long.  There will be a point where the Bank of England decides that worries about a premature interest rate hike outweigh that of the potential long-term costs but we haven’t reached that stage yet.

The caution shown by Carney in his recent statements suggests that the UK has yet to approach a point where higher interest rates can even be discussed as a possibility.  This partly reflects the possible outcomes facing the Bank of England.  A stalled economic recovery that results from a hike in interest rates would be one of the most dreaded outcomes for a central bank.  On the other hand, the effects of problems such as a housing bubble or excessive debt are only felt years later.

Low inflation adds to the reasons why the Bank of England might take a more cautious approach.  Inflation is not likely to cause trouble anytime soon given weak gains in wages and a strong pound.  A further factor to consider is that the Bank of England will feel the need to forewarn both borrowers and investors that higher interest rates are on their way.  All this points to a hike to interest rates being a bogeyman for some time to come.

Monday, 12 May 2014

US Monetary Policy – Investors face stormy future

US investors have been blessed with calm seas of late but their good luck is unlikely to last

Monetary Policy has entered a period of calm after enduring something of a turbulent passage through the global financial crisis.  The unprecedented tempest which buffeted the banking sector led central banks to trial a number of measures never seen before.  Yet, since tapering of quantitative easing was launched at the end of 2013, it has been relatively smooth sailing.  Tapering has been implemented in steady waves so as to not shake the delicate stomachs of investors.  However, rather than signalling the end of the choppy weather in the financial markets, the current lull could just be the eye of the storm.

Skies clear following predictable monetary policy

Investors prefer favourable conditions in the same way as sailors.  A view far ahead to the horizon is prized in the financial markets as well as by mariners.  One element that helps investors to better plan a course for the future is having a predictable monetary policy as a guide.  Investors had come to rely too much on the Federal Reserve as a steady hand at the helm using quantitative easing to put some wind back in the sails of the US economy.  Problems thus arose when the Federal Reserve first floated the idea of trimming back its expansive monetary policy in the middle of 2013.

What was a stiff breeze for the US hit many emerging markets like a financial hurricane.  This is because a considerable portion of the money printed in the US had travelled the globe in search of more bountiful returns.  Some developing countries had become a haven for the extra cash but the money left in a whirlwind once the prospects for returns in the US picked up.  The resulting market turbulence pushed some countries to the brink of going under, but investors eventually settled down again after adjusting to the new forecasts.

The outlook for US monetary policy has brightened considerably with the steady progression of tapering.  The Federal Reserve has cut back its purchasing of bonds by US$10 billion at each of its meetings, which happen almost every month.  As a result, bond purchases have been reduced a few times already in 2014 and fell from US$85 billion in late 2013 to US$45 billion at the most recent meeting at the end of April.  The predictability of US monetary policy also survived the potential shipwreck that was the change in skipper from Ben Bernanke to Janet Yellen at the beginning of the year.

Forecast for storms ahead

All is well for now.  However, there may be trouble on the horizon as tapering is just the start of the Federal Reserve relinquishing its role of propping up the economy.  A bigger storm may be coming next year as interest rates have to be raised from their current record low levels.  The Federal Reserve has pledged not to change interest rates for a while as it monitors the economic recovery.  Interest rate hikes must happen sometime in the next year or so especially in light of the surprising improvements in the US job market.

The end of quantitative easing and higher interest rates are all part of a voyage back to normality.  It has been a strange new world in terms of both the financial markets and monetary policy following the waves of financial havoc over the past several years.  The recent squalls that hit emerging markets can be seen as a necessary part of this journey.  Nevertheless, other rough patches may still lie ahead considering that it is far from normal for US stocks to be pushing on record highs despite slow economic growth

While it is tough to gauge what normal should look like in terms of the financial markets, the signs indicate that rough seas lie ahead.  Emerging markets have already taken a beating which makes it likely that the next storm may strike US investors closer to home.  

Thursday, 3 April 2014

Tax Hike in Japan to test fight against Deflation

The Japanese government has been proactive in its battle with deflation but higher consumption taxes will show how much progress has actually been made

There is a big test coming up for the Prime Minister of Japan, Shinzo Abe, and his own brand of economic policies which have been labelled “Abenomics”.  Abe has launched a range of aggressive measures to end deflation and get the Japanese economy moving again.  However, a rise in the consumption tax from 5% to 8% in April will provide a thorough examination of the economic recovery in Japan.  The results will matter not only for the long-suffering Japanese citizens but may also provide crucial lessons on how to combat the growing threat of deflation.

Economic Policy - could do better

A report card for Japan's Prime Minister might see him get an “A” for effort but a “C” for execution.  Abe has had a busy first year in power and has attracted plaudits for his three arrows of economic policy encompassing fiscal stimulus, monetary easing, and structural reforms.  This has translated into 10.3 trillion yen (or around US$100 billion) in extra government spending and the Japanese central bank aiming to double the money supply over a two year period.

Hopes were buoyed as the Japanese economy perked up in early 2013 while the stock market in Japan was one of the best performers last year.  Unfortunately, Abenomics did not live up to the hype with economic growth slowing and many investors selling their Japanese shares in 2014.  The shortfall against expectations has been due to an unwillingness to push through the reforms which are key to getting the economy moving again.

Your Neighbourhood Economist had always been sceptical about the outlook for the reforms as Abe is a conservative in a political party which is known as a bastion of old-school traditions in Japan.  The Japanese government is not alone in using expansionary monetary policy as a shortcut to improving the economy.  Yet, two decades of stagnation show that there is no easy route to scoring good marks where the economy in Japan is concerned.

Economic recovery put to the test

The hike in the consumption tax (which has been on the cards for decades) is a move to sort out the government finances but threatens the goal of defeating deflation.  Consumer prices have begun to edge upwards but this depends on the central bank in Japan continuing to print a torrent of new yen notes.  Rising prices are a novelty in Japan after decades of deflation with the higher consumption tax set to bump prices up a further notch.

It is not clear whether Japan is ready for this real-life lesson on the effects of inflation.  Many companies in Japan are not yet convinced that inflation has taken hold with some even lowering prices to absorb the higher taxes.  As a result, wage gains have been timid despite the government's efforts to bully Japanese firms into paying their workers more.  Inflation without higher wages is even worse than deflation as consumers increasingly feel the pinch.  The increase in consumption tax could exacerbate this trend and depress spending.

Little to learn

A poor showing in economic policy in Japan will seldom make the news elsewhere but it does not bode well as other places look set to face a similar set of problems.  The causes of deflation in Japan are becoming more prevalent in Europe – high government debts, an ageing population, a stagnating economy, and companies struggling amid globalization.

Lessons learnt in Japan could be applied elsewhere.  Yet, successes have been few and far between.  Japan does not make a good case study for fiscal stimulus (more due to problems within Japan rather than problems with the idea of a stimulus).  Neither has monetary policy had much impact with an increase in the supply of money only having a limited effect on inflation (due to the link between money supply and inflation being weaker than assumed).  Europe is instead contemplating negative interest rates which is something that Japan has not tried.

Too much inflation will drag down the grades of central banks but deflation could earn them a fail.  Part of the reason is that deflation has been seen as a cause of the malaise of the Japanese economy (even though deflation is more likely just a symptom).  If the Japanese economy could return to being the star pupil it was in the 1980s, deflation would no longer come with such a bad reputation.

Tuesday, 1 April 2014

Interest rates - how not to manage the money supply

How central banks thought they had slain the main threat to the economy but the real menace was lurking elsewhere

Economics is a narrative on how the economy is supposed to work, but the path to economic success and riches is often fraught with danger.  The cautionary tale of interest rates and money supply serves as one such example.  The hero of the story was meant to be central banks whose role was to control monetary policy which involves looking after the amount of money in the economy.  Interest rates were deemed the best weapon to regulate the money supply and a couple of decades of success ingrained a belief in this view of the world.  However, the global financial crisis put an end to hopes for a happy ending and economists are still struggling to come up with a new script.

What was supposed to happen

The original scenario relied on central banks being able to influence the money supply by setting interest rates to the appropriate level.  Central banks would not target money supply directly but focus on inflation instead.  Economic theory states that inflation is the result of an expanding amount of money in the economy.  More money equals higher prices.  So, if prices are rising too fast, this is due to an excess of money in the economy.  Higher interest rates act as a damper on inflation because the amount of money moving around the economy drops off as the demand for loans falls and consumers leave more cash in the bank.

The focus on inflation also stemmed from its leading role in telling how well the economy was doing.   Inflation has gotten out of hand and wreaked havoc in the past so economists are determined that this storyline was not to be repeated.  Inflation is also easy to keep tabs on compared to money supply which is tough to define, let alone measure (the money supply could include cash as well as money in banks (current or savings accounts) and other funds).

All good in theory.  And it even worked in practice for a couple of decades from the late 1980s.  Economists thought that their ideas had enabled them to conquer inflation and smooth out the boom and bust cycles.  But all of the good work of economic policy was undone due to an inherent flaw in the theory.  Growth in money supply not only affects consumer prices, which central banks watched over-closely, but also in asset prices, which were not seen as a concern.

Need for a new narrative

It is no surprise that the villain in this story is the banking sector.  Banks were left in charge of setting the money supply which rises and falls depending on the amount of lending.  The volume of loans (along with the money supply) exploded during the favourable economic conditions over the years leading up to the global financial crisis.  Banks were able to take advantage of the growing demand for credit due to innovations in finance that meant that banks could pass loans onto others and not have to worry about loan repayments. 

A large portion of the loans was used to buy existing assets such as houses or shares.  The resulting gains in asset prices, which surged ahead of growth in the underlying economy, sowed the seeds for the crisis to come.  Meanwhile, a dramatic increase in global trade meant that inflation was no longer determined in the domestic economy but was highly influenced by global markets.  Cheap imports from China reduced the prices of products like clothes and electronics.  Imports were also on the rise and the prices of any internationally traded goods no longer depended on the money supply in any one economy.

Subdued inflation meant that the results of the rampant increase in money supply did not jump out at central banks.  Their focus on consumer inflation led central banks to disregard the asset price bubble growing in their midst.  Instead, it was argued that financial markets would always set the appropriate prices and that central banks should not get involved.  The irony is that any extra cash tends to influence asset prices even more than consumer prices (as shown by the effects of quantitative easing) but this effect is near impossible to separate from other factors (hence the reliance on inflation).

It was revealed that central banks had been setting interest rates too low to keep the economy from getting into trouble.  The whole messy chapter could have been avoided if the money supply had been kept under control.  A simple solution would be for the economy to be left to its own devices with a relatively stable money supply.  Greater demand for loans would push up interest rates, stopping debt levels from becoming excessive while also benefiting savers. 

Despite the obvious solution, economists are loath to give up on the fairy tale they always believed would come true.  It may take time for a new economic story to be written but the changes should mean a brighter turn in the future of the economy.  With this, at least the sobering ending to the latest chapter of the economy should come with a silver lining.